Tuesday, July 31, 2012

DeLong on Friedman in 2006

This is one of those pieces of writing I had trouble excerpting, so you get it all. Two things I would disagree with. First, the claim that Keynes underestimated monetary policy is exaggerated. Second I disagree with all but the first sentence of the paragraph about Keynes and technocracy. On the first point, I have some details in my RAE article and on the second point I have details in a paper I have yet to write (damn you unidirectional time!).

But this really ought to be a reflection on Friedman, not Keynes, so you don't need to worry about the details on those right now anyway. Here's Brad DeLong:

"Friedman Completed Keynes

The most famous and influential American economist of the past century died in November. Milton Friedman was not the most famous and influential economist in the world -- that honor belongs to John Maynard Keynes. But Milton Friedman ran a close second.

From one perspective, Milton Friedman was the star pupil of, successor to, and completer of Keynes’s work. Keynes, in his General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money , set out the framework that nearly all macroeconomists use today. That framework is based on spending and demand, the determinants of the components of spending, the liquidity-preference theory of short-run interest rates, and the requirement that government make strategic but powerful interventions in the economy to keep it on an even keel and avoid extremes of depression and manic excess. As Friedman said, “We are all Keynesians now.”

But Keynes’s theory was incomplete: his was a theory of employment, interest, and money. It was not a theory of prices. To Keynes’s framework, Friedman added a theory of prices and inflation, based on the idea of the natural rate of unemployment and the limits of government policy in stabilizing the economy around its long-run growth trend – limits beyond which intervention would trigger uncontrollable and destructive inflation.

Moreover, Friedman corrected Keynes’s framework in one very important respect. The experience of the Great Depression led Keynes and his more orthodox successors to greatly underestimate the role and influence of monetary policy. Friedman, in a 30-year campaign starting with his and Anna J. Schwartz’s A Monetary History of the United States , restored the balance. As Friedman also said, “and none of us are Keynesian.”

From another perspective, Friedman was the arch-opponent and enemy of Keynes and his successors. Friedman and Keynes both agreed that successful macroeconomic management was necessary - that the private economy on its own might well be subject to unbearable instability ­and that strategic, powerful, but limited economic intervention by the government was necessary to maintain stability. But, while for Keynes, the key was to keep the sum of government spending and private investment stable, for Friedman the key was to keep the money supply -- the amount of purchasing power in readily spendable form in the hands of businesses and households-- stable.

A relatively minor, technical difference in means, you might say. A difference of opinion that rested on different judgments about how the world works, which could (and ultimately was) resolved by empirical research, you might say. And you would be half right. For this difference in means, tactics, and empirical judgments rested on top of deep gulf in Keynes’s and Friedman’s moral philosophy.

Keynes saw himself as the enemy of laissez-faire and an advocate of public management. Clever government officials of goodwill, he thought, could design economic institutions that would be superior to the market -- or could at least tweak the market with taxes, subsidies, and regulations to produce superior outcomes. It was simply not the case, Keynes argued, that the private incentives of those active in the marketplace were aligned with the public good. Technocracy was Keynes’s faith: skilled experts designing and fine-tuning institutions out of the goodness of their hearts to make possible general prosperity -- as Keynes, indeed, did at Bretton Woods where the World Bank and IMF were created.

Friedman disagreed vociferously. In his view, it usually was the case that private market interests were aligned with the public good: episodes of important and significant market failure were the exception, rather than the rule, and laissez-faire was a good first approximation. Moreover, Friedman believed that even when private interests were not aligned with public interests, that government could not be relied on to fix the problem.

Government failures, Friedman argued, were greater and more terrible than market failures. Governments were corrupt. Governments were inept. The kinds of people who staffed governments were the kinds of people who liked ordering others around.

At the same time, Friedman believed that even when the market equilibrium was not the utilitarian social-welfare optimum, and even when government could be used to improve matters from a utilitarian point of view, there was still an additional value in letting human freedom have the widest berth possible. There was, Friedman believed, something intrinsically bad about government commanding and ordering people about -- even if the government did know what it was doing.

I do not know whether Keynes or Friedman was more right in their deep orientation. But I do think that the tension between their two views has been a very valuable driving force for human progress over the past hundred years."

4 comments:

  1. Regarding Keynes and technocracy...I think you might want to go to Volume XXVII of the CWJMK, which Dr. Michael Emmett Brady cites as support for the notion that J.M. Keynes rejected Neo-Keynesian-style demand management.

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. Also, on another note folks, here's an article by Sylvie Rivot in Italy's History of Economic Ideas: "Where to draw the line between laissez-faire and planning? Keynes and Friedman on public and semi-public institutions".

      http://www.libraweb.net/articoli.php?chiave=201106102&rivista=61

      Delete
  2. Why don't you explain the details of the paper you have yet to write here? Then you will have written it!

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. :)

      On a second reading, it's not quite as disagreeable as I had taken it to be. I think there's a very real extent to which Keynes doubted what clever policymakers could do, and he made many references to the fact that goodwill and cleverness would not do - that implementing macro policy would very much be a matter of trial and error and would likely vary considerably between societies. While I can see the appeal of "technocracy", I don't think he was that optimistic.

      A lot of institutions he had a hand in, like Bretton Woods, were institutional or constitutional orders specifically designed to contain the the failures of clever policymakers with goodwill.

      He also discusses at length in The End of Laissez Faire exactly what he has in mind when he speaks of the socialization of investment. A lot of what he talks about is a natural socialization in large joint-stock companies. Like Berle and Means, Keynes put great stock in these developments - there are a lot of ties between the separation of ownership and control and the euthanasia of the rentier. Keynes pointed out (I believe here, or perhaps it was somewhere else) that the locus of control over the economy should be somewhere between the individual and the State.

      Like I said - I like the paragraph better on a second reading. But I do think, if I were to sketch out Keynes's political economy, it would emphasize some different themes.

      Delete

All anonymous comments will be deleted. Consistent pseudonyms are fine.